The Causes for Child Labour in India: the
Poverty Analysis
G.K. Lieten
Many exercises have been done on the delineation of the causes of child
labour. In my analysis, I shall make a twofold distinction. On the one hand
I shall make a distinction between the pull process and the push process.
Economists particularly have focussed the investigation on the rational
choice process within the child labour family, an autonomous choice that
is seen to be associated with such variables as poverty and illiteracy. On
the other hand, I shall distinguish forms of child labour. In all languages,
different words exist for different types of activities in which products,
services, artefacts and mental constructs are produced. The English
language has words like labour, work, toil, occupation, employment;
Hindi has such words as shram, kam, mehnat, rozgar, mazduri, etc. An
explanation for the phenomenon of child labour, as I shall argue, will have
to start by separating categories before meaningful statistics, and
multivariate analysis based on those statistics, can be produced.
Statistical exercises, on the basis of different sets of data (for example
Cigno et al., 2001, Kannan 2001, Ramachandran and Massün 2002, Giri
National Labour Institute 2000) have established that child labour is
positively related, among other factors, with poverty, education,
agriculture, and the overall work participation ratio.
The V.V. Giri National Labour Institute, for example, has studied the
inter-district differentials in various variables that may have a correlation
with child labour. In respect of a number of states, some correlations stand
out, but they usually do not show a uniform pattern across the different
states that have been studied. There is the suggestion of an inverse
relationship between for example rural male and female literacy and child
labour and between the general development index and the incidence of
child labour. Statistics and correlation exercises work on the assumption
that all variables have been clearly defined, that these variables, in
combination or taken separately, represent the causal factors, and that the
number of observations is sufficiently large to lead to meaningful
conclusions. The three conditions are not necessarily fulfilled, and the
statistical conclusions hence apparently hang in the air. We are made to accept that in all states there is ‘a strong inverse
correlation between rural literacy rates and incidence of child labour’, and
that ‘strengthening of rural literacy programmes would lead to nearly 50
per cent decline in the incidence of child labour’ (National Labour
Institute 2000, booklet on Bihar: 2). These correlations, in a statistical
sense indeed may exist, but a quick look at the cases selected in Table 1, a
selection I should add that was done purposefully with an eye on the
outliers, informs us that there are significant differences, within states and
particularly between states.
Table 1. Examples of Child Labour-prone Districts.
Incidence (%) of
Child Labour
%Total Rural
Literacy Rate
% Workers in
Agriculture
RID
Jhabua (Madhya Pradesh) 25.2 13.4 90.4 84
Surguja (Madhya Pradesh) 11.1 24.98 4.3 46
Durg (Madhya Pradesh) 5.5 50.4 70.0 80
Kurnool (Andhra Pradesh) 14.1 33.3 75.2 83
Mahboodnagar(Andhra
Pradesh)
14.6 25.3 83.4 53
Saharsa (Bihar) 6.0 26.9 91.0 24
Dumka (Bihar) 7.9 31.5 85.5 32
Kalahandi (Orissa) 12.5 27.9 85.6 51
Koraput (Orissa) 12.7 17.4 84.7 54
Periyar (Tamil Nadu) 8.5 53.8 75.4 128
Kamarajar (Tamil Nadu) 8.9 55.7 52.7 115
Dharampuri (Tamil Nadu) 8.1 43.3 80.8 79
Note: RID (Rural Development Index) derives from a weighted
combination of various indicators such as the importance of industry, the
spread of bank services, literacy, etc.
Source: National Labour Institute 2000.
There obviously is an observable (and calculable) correlation. For
example, Jhabua (Madhya Pradesh) has a child labour incidence of 25.5 %
and a total literacy rate of 13.4 %. Durg on the other hand has 5.5 % and
50.4 % respectively. But some districts have a high child labour incidence
under conditions that are not necessarily worse than conditions in other
districts and in other states. Why should Mahboobnagar and Kurnool
(Andhra Pradesh) have a child labour incidence of 14.6 % and 14.1 %
respectively? They have a total literacy rate of 25.3 % and 33.3 %. Why
should Saharsa (Bihar) have a child labour incidence of only 5.9 % (rural
literacy rate is 26.9 %) whereas Kalahandi in Orissa has a comparable
literacy rate and a much higher incidence of child labour. Periyar (Tamil
Nadu) on the other hand has a child labour ratio comparable to Dumka in Bihar but it has almost double the rural literacy levels. In respect of the
variables ‘agricultural orientation’ and ‘overall development’ similar
‘anomalies’ can be found.
Looking at the data, one observes too many anomalies which hollow the
claims made in correlation exercises. My argument at this stage is not
whether correlations do exist, but rather that the basis on which the
calculations are done is flawed by an ill-definition of child labour.
Clarity of Definition
In the statistics, various forms of ‘child labour’ are generally collapsed
into one. Care should be taken to isolate child labour as a category
separate from ‘child work’ and ‘child deprivation’. By adding up all
children that in one way or the other are not attending school full-time or
are attending school but are engaged in some ‘working activity’ or the
other, the incidence of child labour has been blown out of proportion.
According to some sources (see e.g. Weiner 1991 and Human Rights
Watch 1996), India is supposed to have more than 100 million working
children.
The high numbers are part of a reconstructed reality, a definitional
deception, which elsewhere (Lieten 2002) I have referred to as the called
this the mixing of apples, oranges and bananas. Neera Burra, an author
whose writings have helped to focus the public attention on child labour
(see Burra 1995), writes explicitly that a working child is ‘basically a
child who is deprived of the right to education…. What makes this
definition important is that it makes it unambiguously clear that all out-ofschool children are child labourers in one way or another’ (Burra 1997: 8).
Mahendra Dev and C. Ravi (in Ramachandran and Massün 2002: 193)
also consider a broadening of the definition ‘by defining a child labourer
as one who is deprived of the right to education and childhood.’
It is one thing to draw the attention to the failure of a government (and a
society) to look after all its children in an even-handed manner, and
provide them access to quality education and health services. It is another
thing to compound the various manifestations of negligence in one
composite category, which is fairly inadequate for analysis and for policy
purposes. The fruit bowl thus constructed indeed is attractive in the sense
that it forcefully draws the public attention to the acute social injustice
that still affects the majority of the children in India. It, however, also
encumbers the search for causal factors and policy solutions.
If we want to know the reasons why children are ‘nowhere’, i.e. neither in
school nor in a work place, the explanatory factors need not be related to
the factors that are at the root cause of why children do hard labour. The
various learned multivariate probit and regression analysis exercises do
not make that distinction. Independent correlates in such exercises are
calculated to have a positive or negative impact on child labour.
Conclusions then often suggest that poverty, nutritional poverty, indebtedness, literacy, work participation, the number of children and the
size of the cattle herd are important factors.
The problem with these exercises, however, is that ‘child labour’ is not a
definitionally segregated category. The variable ‘mothers’ literacy’ may
have a different impact on girls working in the household and boys
working on the family farm after school time or during school time on the
one hand, and on boys and girls working in stone quarries, in restaurants,
in workshops, etc. on the other hand. Whereas the former activities fall
under child work, and can be considered as a valuable aspect of
socialisation, the latter are directly related to the sale or hire of labour
power and may interfere with the normal physical, intellectual,
psychological and emotional development of the child. The clubbing all
these different types of ‘labour’ together in econometric models (using
Census of NSS data) is unlikely to produce sound results, and is unlikely
to explain for much of the mechanism that perpetuates child labour. The
data are culled from a fruit bowl of meanings and for a sound analysis, the
different types of work/labour should first be disentangled.
I shall later argue that authors who put the responsibility for child labour
on the parents of the child labourer itself, rather than on a system, or an
entrepreneurial class. I first intend to look at two explanatory variables:
culture and poverty.
Tradition
Traditional modes of living, dating back to a culture in which work was
not a distinguishable activity but was tied up with routine, did not
distinguish between work and labour. Children were gradually initiated
into the world of the adults. Quite a lot of what has been subsumed under
child labour, and as such has entered the statistics, is work performed
during a standard process of socialisation. Most of the child labourers in
Africa and Asia reside in the countryside and assist on the family farm.
The opportunity to do such work, in the transition from toddler to
adulthood, is something to be encouraged. The child is being socialized in
a manner that prepares it for its future tasks and life style in a specific
community in a specific society. Light work, which does not pre-empt the
other essential activities of children, can constitute a gradual initiation into
adulthood and a positive element in the child’s development. It may also
have a qualitative impact on work attitudes in general.
In developing countries there tends to be a difference, even a rift, between
manual workers and the (male and female) elite. The ‘work’ practice at a
young age (cleaning, washing up, repair work, digging, weeding, and a
host of other activities) may help to better understand, to better respect
and to better appreciate the meaning of work and labour. This
consideration is one more reason why the work done by children should
be analytically categorized. Having said this, one should also be weary of attempts to condone the
position as ‘future workers’ that many children are caught in. Many have
argued that the work done by children -on the farm, in the artisanal shop
or in petty trading- has served as a form of apprenticeship, preparing them,
better than any formal or informal school system could, for the income
generating profession in adulthood. It is an argument that can be found in
many books produced by Third World scholars who wish to stress the
cultural exclusivity of their tradition. In the overview by Mishra and
Pande (1996: 5), the exponents of the socialization theory of child labour
argue that the socio-cultural framework of peasant societies ‘emit such
socio-economic processes whereby the use of child labour is socialized as
an integral part of family-oriented social and institutional order’.
The assumption behind the argument is that socialization within the poor
family, with its different norms and expectations, is different from the
norms and expectations associated with the modernizing state. Such an
argument, rather than poverty, was also noticeable in the report of the
Department of Labor of the US Government, written after senators Tom
Harkin and George Brown had introduced the Child Labor Deterrence
Bill:
The general perception in Asia is that children should work to develop
a sense of responsibility and develop a career…. It is argued that child
employment apparently teaches children of the poor to acquire moral
and ethical attitudes and work habits at an early age (US Department of
Labor 1994: 24).
The difficulty with this argument is that it assumes that there is something
like a culture of poverty among the marginalized and exploited families at
the bottom of society with its separate norms and aspirations. It separates
the elite from the people and justifies a class-imposed differential
treatment of children. This is the attitude underlying the scathing attack by
Myron Weiner (1991) on the ‘Hindu’ culture. Weiner, in my view has a
myopic and ethnocentric view of Indian culture, but his arguments do
apply to some of the learned high-caste scholars in India who seek to
explain child labour on the basis of ancient cultures and the
exceptionalism of that great Indian tradition. One such source, notably in
an ILO publication on the subject, questions the notion that work is an
unjust imposition on children, and argues that no useful purpose is served
by invoking the need for schooling for all children within a certain age
group:
it is necessary instead to review the place of children in society and to
look into the culturally conceived obligations towards and expectations
from them. ... Value judgments and evaluative standards rooted in and
deriving from Western experience cannot always be meaningfully
superimposed on the social realities of the developing countries (Dube
1981: 179, 182). An official Government of India report of 1977 had stated that child
labour is ‘economically unsound, psychologically disastrous and
physically as well as morally dangerous and harmful…. On account of
their vulnerability and dependence, they can be exploited, ill treated and
directed into undesirable channels by unscrupulous elements in the
community (quoted in Dube 1981: 183). Dube disagrees with such a
position and calls for a better understanding of Indian reality and for
greater conceptual clarity. After going back to the ancient Hindu
scriptures, she places the ancient idea of childhood involving labour in the
context of modern society:
The argument that a cultivator’s son who does not learn to handle the
plough and other instruments at the appropriate age would find it
difficult to handle them later, has sufficient strength. Once it is
assumed by the parents that children are to live and function more or
less in the same society as their own, it stands to reason that the tasks
they have to perform should be learned at a proper age (Dube 1981:
189).
Cultural relativism and cultural exceptionalism may invite the danger of
defending class privileges and class disabilities that are out of tune with
the universal declarations of Human Rights and of the Rights of the Child.
It in any case explains the prevalence of child labour as deriving from a
conscious decision by the parents of the children. It uses ‘national culture’
as an explanatory model.
Poverty
The cultural explanation is not necessarily distinct from the poverty
explanation. It has often been argued that child work was essential to the
survival of the children and their families. It indeed is obvious that, by and
large, poverty is an important reason why children work. If they were not
to work, survival of the entire family could be at stake. Child labour as a
matter of fact can be beneficial to the child, not only in terms of the
preparation for the tasks of adulthood, but also in terms of direct
improvement of health condition. Since labour adds to the family income,
it will add to the nutritional intake of the young worker, and the morbidity
levels of the working child may even be lower than the levels prevailing
among comparable counterparts. With these considerations in mind, it is
not uncommon to divide child labour in four categories, from intolerable
to hazardous and neutral and ending up with varieties of child work,
which even may have a positive impact on the future adult.
Acute poverty is usually advanced as a reason for sending children to
work. This obviously is an explanation, which hardly requires neither
substantiation nor verification. It is common sense to accept that the
poorer the family, the poorer the district, the poorer the country, the higher the incidence of child labour. A closer observation, however, suggests that
this is the case in a restricted sense only.
The first problem with this explanation is that poverty is difficult to define
and that poverty in any case is more than economic poverty. There are
certain thresholds below which people will find it difficult to survive.
These thresholds are defined by nutrition, sanitation, health and shelter. At
the level of deprivation, below these minimum thresholds, there is not
much of an option between work and non-work. Deprivation often comes
as a shock effect: the dead or severe illness of the adult breadwinner has
often been documented to be a direct cause underlying child labour.
Poverty defined as human deprivation goes to the root of the child labour
problem. It relates to many factors that cannot be quantified and cannot be
streamlined into econometric exercises. Deprivation relates to exclusion,
to vulnerability and to ignorance as much as to physical weakness and
lack of property assets. Children living under such conditions, especially
when a shock event has torn normal family life apart, will work in order to
survive. By working, they find an individual answer to calamities for
which society does not take responsibility.
Poverty, as defined traditionally, usually combines with many children per
households, with low literacy and with a horizon of lowly-paid and
unskilled jobs, open to child labour. It hence is not surprising if positive
correlations can be found. They have been found by many. For example,
Cigno, Rosati and Tszannatos (2001), on the basis of data on around 35
thousand households provided by the National Council of Applied
Economic Research, have concluded that child work is negatively
correlated with household income, and that school enrolment is positively
correlated with income. The children in the households with the highest
income levels are less likely to work and to be out of school, but Cigno et
al. (2001) are not, however, concluding that poverty is at the root cause of
child labour. Indeed elsewhere in the Handbook on Child Labour,
produced for the World Bank, they argue that the NCAER survey
establishes that the negative effect of household income on child labour
supply tends to be small:
the elasticity of child labor to household resources is relatively small.
While low income seems to be associated with relatively higher child
labor supply, changes in income do not seem to generate large
reductions in the child labor supply (and) income subsidies are likely to
reduce only relatively small effects. This implies that very large
transfers would be required to significantly alter the situation.
However, transfer of such a magnitude are not economically or
politically feasible (Cigno et al. 2001, chapter 4).
Others have presented findings which suggest that ‘poverty’ is not a
significant variable in explaining child labour. Mahendra Dev and Ravi
(2002: 197) found a robust positive correlation with female work
participation, female literacy and indebtedness of households, but not with
poverty as such: ‘In all our results, poverty as measured by the headcount ratio performed poorly with perverse signs.’ The proportion of boys and
girls from ultra-poor households who participate in household activities,
according to the interesting data basis provided by Chaudhri and Wilson is
actually lower than from their non-poor counterparts. On the other hand,
the incidence of child labour is higher among the poorer households:
‘However, even among the high expenditure non-poor, child labour is not
totally absent, being 40-50 per thousand compared to 81-112 among the
poor’ (Chaudhri and Wilson 2002: 123).
Parents, when they themselves are disabled, may need the work of the
children to keep the household running. In these cases, poverty is very
much at stake as an explanatory variable. Most of the ‘child labour’
referred to in the previous paragraph, however relates to parents allocating
farm work and household work to children. They apparently prefer the
input of their own children over hired labour. Another explanation for
sending children to work is that parents (and children) across the various
categories of non-rich argue that education has a restricted usefulness
only. The sooner the children learn a skill the more beneficial it will be for
the child since it will help him or her to secure a job. Since education has
been experienced not to be helpful -the quality of teaching and the lack of
job prospects even after many years of schooling- it is better to send
children to work than to have them loiter around
The arguments in defence of ‘tolerable forms’ of child labour -as long as
wages and employment opportunities remain below a critical level- are not
without merit. The low levels of income, usually associated with the
absence of countervailing power in the forms of trade unions, may make it
necessary to involve more family members than the standard
‘breadwinner’ in the labour process.
It would be wrong, however, to assume that poverty causes child labour.
Poverty, as many studies have warned, is not the only reason for the
existence of child labour. The picture varies across households and across
regions and countries. Countries or regions which are equally poor may
yet have relatively high or relatively low levels of child labour. A typical
example of a poor region with an exemplary low level of child labour is
Kerala, a state that has been widely acclaimed for its high human
development index. Another example is Sri Lanka where even in the 15-
17 years’ age group only 9.9 % were not attending school and only 25 %
were working, usually while attending school. Sri Lanka, taking the age
category between 5 and 17 years (!), has only 5.4 % and 3.3 % who are
respectively economically active and working in the household without
attending school (IPEC Sri Lanka 1999).
The enormous difference between Pakistan and Sri Lanka or between
Kerala and Andhra Pradesh cannot possibly be explained with reference to
the poverty factor as the sole variable or even the main variable. The
exceptions indicate that it is possible to reduce child labour without
having to wait for the breakthrough in economic development. The impact
of social and political movements, the Buddhist reform movement in Sri Lanka and the leftist movement in Kerala may have changed the social
equilibrium in such a way that education, and other rights to development,
were able to replace the old division of labour. This is a point to which we
shall return in the later pages of this article.
Push and Pull
Up to now, the focus has been on the push factor. Much research on the
causes of child labour indeed tends to concentrate on the supply factors.
Apart from the common view that poverty is pushing poor children into
the labour market, there is also the pre-occupation with the victims, and
the life conditions they have to cope with. Neo-classical economics is
based on the multivariate analysis of supply (and demand) factors. The
individual author is expected to take decisions and to take these decisions
on the basis of a rational choice. The rational choice is conditioned by
various variables (literacy of parents, level of poverty, number of children,
gender, etc.).
Quite a lot of World Bank inspired research has been done (by economists
like Rosati, Cigno, Fallon, Ravallion, Grootaert and Ray) on the axioms
introduced by Basu and Van (1998). The two axioms are defined as the
Luxury Hypothesis and the Substitution Hypothesis. The assumption is on
the one hand that a family will send the children to the labour market only
if the income from adult labour sources drops very low and on the other
hand that adult labour and child labour are substitutes, depending on the
equilibrium in the market and endowments within the family.
The onus for child labour in this frame of mind rests with the family, not
with the employers. The various studies (using Probit regressions) predict
that certain variables within the households have a positive or negative
role to play. Through econometric analysis the probability of a girl of an
illiterate mother in a below poverty level household is tested. The
conclusions then relate to the way parents react to the opportunities and
the challenges. They are the players in the game and the regressions
exercises are meant to calculate how they will play the game. Rajan Ray,
after comparing the age group 10-17 (!) years in Peru and Pakistan rejects
both the Basu/Van hypotheses, the Luxury axiom as well as the
substitution axiom. The poverty coefficient is statistically insignificant.
Crossing the poverty line, Ray (2000a: 9-11) argues, does not reduce the
child labour levels:
The strong rejection by the Pakistani data of any direct link between
economic deprivation and child labour … is consistent with the
observation of Bhatty (1998) who cites a variety of Indian studies on
child labour in support of the view that ‘income and related variables
do not seem to have any direct significant effect on children’s work
input … it is not a financial imperative that forces children to work …
children are often put to work as a deterrent to idling rather than as an
economic necessity’ (p. 1734). The technicality of the regression analysis, and the results it produces,
cannot obviously be questioned. My concern is that the data sets include
children up to the age of 17 and does not appear to be based on a rigorous
definition of child labour. My other concern is that the study argues that
wage increases for the working poor do not bring down child labour, and
that on the contrary adult female wage increases exerts a positive impact
on a household’s propensity to put its children into employment: ‘The
complementarity between adult female labour and child labour … would
appear to be inconsistent with the idea of parental altruism that underlies
the “Substitution Hypothesis”, namely, that mothers will reduce their
children’s work involvement if their own wage conditions improve’ (Ray
2000a: 12).
Statistics, however, can serve different explanatory trajectories. Ray in
another paper (Ray 2000b: 364), looking at the same set of date, argues
that the hypothesized relationship between child labour and household
poverty and between child schooling and household poverty ‘are both
strongly confirmed’ by the Pakistani data: ‘When a Pakistani household
falls into poverty, it increases each child’s involvement in outside, paid
employment … just as the luxury axiom predicts.’ The conclusion is the
reverse of what has been stated in the previous paragraph.
As one of the few perceptive authors, it is to be added, Ray (2000b: 365)
concludes his article with an important caveat: ‘It is also important to look
at child labor from the demand side, using industry-level data. The
existing literature follows the supply side.’ Not only has the demand side
been rejected, the responsibility for child labour has squarely been
assigned to the poor parents themselves: parents, and children, take
decisions wilfully, balancing the pros and cons, and as agents in their own
right opt for earning a living (or an extra income) in the labour market
rather than postponing consumption demands and enter the educational
system.
It is a perception from the outside, which alleges that poor people have
certain ‘axioms’. The evidence of the existence of those axioms is found
in statistical exercises. The non-poor (and often foreign) observers read
the minds of the poor through the medium of statistical data or in some
cases by merely assuming the mindsets of the poor. This attitude has
found its most extreme form in the theory that poor people actually
produce more children in order to make them work. Parents are assumed
to want children as assets to contribute to the short-term needs of the
household. Also Myron Weiner (1991: 186), without much evidence, just
proclaims it to be a well-know fact:
It is well-known that many poor parents bear children in order to
enhance family income. As economists say, children are viewed as
economic assets, not a economic liabilities. Indian policy makers
accept as the basis for policy the fact that childbearing for low-income
Indians is part of their strategy for family survival and well-being. Such assumptions of a ‘well-known fact’ are not based on a detailed study
of why poor families in certain regions often have many children.
Research may indicate the opposite process: children in large families are
more likely to work is because very poor families usually have a high
fertility rate. The higher fertility rate is not associated with a rational
choice strategy of producing more labour power (see Lieten 2000, part 2,
and 2002). As Tim Dyson (1991: 81) has put it: ‘children work because
people have children, rather than people have children because children
work.’
The struggle for survival underlies the need to work. That is the push
factor in the poverty-stricken families. But there also should be a pull
factor at work, the external force which pulls children towards the
furnaces and the looms, towards the kilns, the quarries and the brothels. In
research, the pull factor should receive more attention, as also suggested
by the ILO (1996: 18):
Research on the causes of child labour tends to concentrate on the
supply factors both because of justifiable pre-occupation with the
victims, and because of the commonly shared view that poverty is the
driving force. But the demand for child labour plays a critical role in
determining the involvement of children in hazardous work.
Segmented Labour Market
One would imagine that the profit motive is the foremost causal factor on
the pull side. The ‘nimble finger’ usually stands out as an important factor.
It is contended that to contend that employers in certain industries prefer
the child labour hands as being more dexterous and more productive.
However, studies conducted by the ILO, for example, have argued that the
prevalence of specific skills or specific dexterity does not cut much ice. In
the industries where the argument is being used, for example in carpet
weaving, diamond polishing and sport goods stitching, adults and children
work side by side. When some of the tasks are performed exclusively by
children, the skills required are so minimal that child labour is clearly
replaceable by (male or female) adult labour. Profit margins would drop
only marginally if child labour were to be replaced by adult labour (Anker
and Barge 1998; see also Chandrashekar 1997, Sharma et al. 2001).
Under conditions of an excess supply of labour, which is usually the case
in child labour-prone areas, one could moreover expect employers to
employ adults rather than children. The downward pressure on wages,
which is bound to occur in an environment of a weak or non-existent
collective bargaining power and of an abundant supply of (adult) labour,
would ultimately lower adult wages to a level hardly above the level of
child wages. Since this has not happened, the suggestion is that adult
labourers, after all, do have a bargaining power, which keeps the wages
and the labour circumstances at somewhat higher levels. The bargaining power usually consists of alternative employment, either
on a small piece of land or in a different segment of the labour market. It
is a combination, which Engels has sarcastically referred to as the
‘blessing’ of landownership for the modern worker in the Irish and
German domestic industry in the 19
th
Century:
Competition permits the capitalist to deduct from the price of labour
power that which the family earns from its own little garden or field. …
Here we see clearly that what at an earlier historical stage was the basis
of relative well-being for the workers, namely, the combination of
agriculture and industry, the ownership of house, garden and field, and
certainly of a dwelling place, is becoming today, under the rule of
large-scale industry, not only the worst hindrance to the worker, but the
greatest misfortune for the whole working class, the basis for an
unexampled depression of wages below their normal level (Engels
1872: 303).
With the growth of capitalism, semi-proletarisation is associated with the
growth of labour market segmentation with a set of submarkets with
different employment conditions and different labour profiles. Such
markets are served by members of poor families depending on their
overall endowments. Some sectors are served by the poorest families,
often as landless migrants moving around and taking up work as
collectives. In some industries, for example in the stone quarries and in
crop-cutting in agriculture, the labour units consists of all work-able
members of the family. Other sectors draw on the child labour force,
leaving the adults to work on a small plot of land or in a separate job.
Under conditions of high unemployment and social polarization, Rodgers
and Standing (1981: 36) have argued, the prospects of breaking out of the
submarket regime are limited. The vast majority of the poor are cut-off
from higher-status, higher-wage jobs, and in competing for the jobs
available to them, relatively low wages are driven down further: ‘So the
pattern of supply of workers to different types of job can be expected to
strengthen labour market segmentation.’
The segmentation of the job market usually occurs in an environment in
which there is a reasonably high demand for labour and a low degree of
labour empowerment. Under such circumstances, employers on the
demand side have created selective markets for labour in addition to a
labour market for (male and female) adults. It is actually not necessarily
the high levels of unemployment that structure the labour market, but
rather the power of the entrepreneurs to access the labour market
unhindered by countervailing power. Child labour actually correlates with
high levels of employment and gets drawn into one segment of the labour
market.
Table 2 indicates that if there is a significant correlation with child labour,
it is between child labour and overall economic participation rates,
particularly female participation rates. It is significant to note, as we have
indicated earlier, that the states with the highest child labour incidence (child labour as an ill-defined category though) are also states with a high
per capita state domestic product. These states (Andhra Pradesh,
Karnataka, Himachal Pradesh, and Tamil Nadu) have a much higher
(female) work participation rate than for example Bihar, Assam, Uttar
Pradesh and West Bengal.
Table 2. Child Labour, Literacy, Income and Work Participation Across
States.
Child
Labour
Per capita
domestic product
Female
Literacy
Work
Participation
Al l Female
Andhra Pradesh 17.8 7006 24.8 81.0 72.4
Karnataka 13.9 7242 34.6 74.9 61.3
Himachal 13.6 6896 51.5 79.9 72.9
Rajasthan 12.2 5315 15.0 77.6 67.2
Tamil Nadu 10.4 8051 42.8 74.8 64.7
Madhya Pradesh 8.7 5516 22.1 76.5 63.0
Orissa 7.4 4662 30.5 65.3 45.7
Maharashtra 6.5 12010 39.7 77.7 70.5
West Bengal 5.1 6247 40.7 58.9 28.5
Uttar Pradesh 5.0 4794 22.9 61.9 34.7
Gujarat 4.1 9054 36.1 73.2 57.9
Bihar 3.7 3417 19.7 56.6 26.9
Punjab 2.7 12934 43.9 58.7 32.4
Assam 2.6 5520 52.1 54.5 23.9
Haryana 2.6 12934 43.9 58.7 32.4
Kerala 0.8 6524 81.7 53.4 32.5
Note: Domestic product in Rs; the other columns in percentages.
Source: NSS 50th Round in Dev and Ravi 2002.
The data in Table 2 have been used for Figure 1, a scatter diagram, which
clearly shows that (female) work participation has a strong influence on
the prevalence of child labour. In general, one observes a positive
correlation between the two indicators. The two outliers are Maharashtra
and Gujarat. The states with the lowest child labour incidence, are also
states with a reasonably low female work participation. Kerala, Haryana,
Assam, Bihar, and Punjab, despite stark differences in other variables, also
have a low child labour incidence. The inference is in line with the theory
of labour market segmentation and complementarity stated above: under
conditions of a high demand for labour in the lower segments of the labour
market, poor families will be tapped for additional labour power: after the
adult male and adult female labour power also the child labour power will be pulled into employment, as is the case in the match industry in
Sivakasi, where working families often combined factory work with work
in the home and/or service in other business sectors
Factory managers thus found themselves with influence not only over
the productive performance of the workers but also over a substantial
part of their social life. This endowed them with an unusual degree of
power…. Employers were thus not solely responsible for the cost of
sustenance and reproduction of the labourers, which may have been a
contributory factor in the low wage levels within the industry (Hilding
2004: 179).
The demand side, constituted historically with a specific labour market
segmentation, creates a specific demand for workers, and once such
segmentation has become the custom (like the demand for child labour in
the match factories, the carpet sheds, the glass industry and the gem
industry), wages and employment conditions are such that adult labour is
excluded from competition with child labour.
The natural order of things under capitalism is to produce as cheaply and
trouble-free as possible. Under ‘normal’ labour conditions as they
emerged in the course of the history of capitalism, wages have risen to a
level which allows for the maintenance of a family, including the extended
reproduction of labour power and the leisure associated with it. In many
sectors of Third World countries, however, the reward for labour has been
maintained at levels below the reproduction needs of labour families. The
segmentation of the labour market leaves the most vulnerable and
marginalized families to fend for survival at the lower end of the income
scale. Indebtedness, illness, failed marriages and social exclusion help to
push the most impoverished families into labour conditions where wages
are far below the family reproduction level.
Conclusions
For an efficient and realistic intervention in policy matters, a
differentiation needs to be made of the different categories of
disenfranchised children: the labouring child, the working-cum-schooling
child and various other disabled children who are usually referred to as
nowhere children. A clear analysis will also help us to have a better
understanding of the causes of child labour, although one should add that
causes tend to be multivariate, and that explanations need to be found in
the structure (of poverty, modes of employment, labour relations, etc.) as
well as in agency.
Many exercises aimed at finding correlations have treated ‘child labour’ as
an all-inclusive category. Using such a category will add to the confusion.
One need not go into complicated exercises to establish that child labour
has something to do with poverty, literacy, high fertility, etc., and we have suggested to look at causes after first having separated child labour from
child work and nowhere children. After we have isolated ‘child labour’ as
such, we could then to look more at the pull forces than at the push forces.
After from shifting some of the blame away from parents to child labour
employers, it would help us to explain the paradox of high poverty areas
with low child labour incidence and the other way round. In areas where
one could expect more push forces because of poverty and illiteracy, child
labour incidence is lower than in areas where levels of poverty and
illiteracy are considerably lower. Our suggestion is that the specific labour
market segmentation, with a low reward for labour power and high levels
of employment under conditions of social, economic and political
submissiveness, is a key to an explanatory model.
Literature
Anker, Richard, Sandhya Barge et al. (1998). Economics of Child Labour
in Hazardous Industries in India. Baroda: Centre for Operations
Research and Training.
Basu, K. and P.H. Van (1998). ‘The Economics of Child Labor’.
American Economic Review, No 3: 412-27.
Bhatty, K. (1998). ‘Educational Deprivation in India: A Survey of Field
Investigation’. Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33, No 27: 1731-
40 and No 28: 1858-69.
Burra, N. (1995). Born to Work: Child Labour in India. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Burra, Neera (1997). Impact Assessment Manual Child Rights. New
Delhi: Embassy of Norway.
Chandrasekhar, C.P. (1997). ‘The Economic Consequences of the
Abolition of Child Labour: An Indian Case Study’. The Journal of
Peasant Studies, Vol. 24, No 3: 137-79.
Chaudhri, D.P. (1997). ‘Female Child Labour and Gender Bias in School
Education in Indian States’. Indian Journal of Labour Economics
40(3): 493-505.
Chaudhri, D.P. and E.J. Wilson (2002). ‘Nutritional Poverty, School
Education and Supply of Child Labour: Explorations with States,
Districts and Household Data for Rural India’. In: Ramachandran and
Massün, eds. (2002): 113-42.
Cigno, Alessandro and Furio C. Rosati (2001). Child Labor, Education,
Fertility and Survival in Rural India. Paper Irewoc Conference on Child
Labour in South Asia, 15-17 October, JNU, New Delhi.
Cigno, Alessandro, Furio C. Rosati and Zafiris Tzannatos (2001). Child
Labor Handbook. Washington: The World Bank, manuscript.
Dev, Mahendra S. and C. Ravi (2002). ‘Food Security and Child Work in
South India: Determinants and Policies’. In: Ramachandran and Massün, eds. (2002): 192-215.
Dube, Leela (1981). ‘The Economic Roles of Children in India.
Methodological Issues’. In: Gerry Rodgers and Guy Standing, The
Economic Roles of Children in Low-Income Countries. Geneva: ILO:
179-214.
Dyson, Tim (1991), ‘Child Labour and Fertility: An Overview, an
Assessment, and an Alternative Framework’, in Ramesh Kanbargi:
Child Labour in the Indian Subcontinent. Dimensions and
Implications, New Delhi/London: Sage, pp. 81-100.
Engels, Friedrich (1872). The Housing Question. In K. Marx and F.
Engels: Selected Works. Moscow: Progress Publishers (1969), Volume
2: 295-375.
Fallon, P. and Z. Tszannatos (1998). Child Labor. Issues and Directions
for the World Bank. Washington: The World Bank.
Giri National Labour Institute (2000). Tools for Convergence, 1974-1999.
New Delhi: National Resource Centre on Child Labour (various
booklets).
Grootaert, C. and Kanbur, R. (1995). ‘Child Labour: An Economic
Perspective’. International Labour Review, Vol. 134, No. 2, pp 187-
203.
Hilding, Per (2004). ‘Workers and Entrepreneurs in the Sivakasi Match
Industry’. In: G.K. Lieten, Ravi Srivastava and S. Thorat: Small Hands
in South Asia. Child Labour in Perspective. New Delhi: Manohar.
Human Rights Watch (1996). The Small Hands Of Slavery. Bonded Child
Labor in India. Internet version:www.hrw.org.
ICFTU (1996). No Time to Play. Child Workers in the Global Economy.
Brussels: International Confederation of Free Trade Unions (internet
version).
ILO (1996). Child Labour. Targetting the Intollerable. Geneva: ILO,
Report VII.
IPEC Sri Lanka (1999). Summary Findings of Child Labour Survey in Sri
Lanka.
(www.ilo.org/public/english/standards/ipec/simpoc/srilanka/report/srila
n99).
Kannan, K.P., ed. (2001). Economics of Child Labour. New Delhi: Deep
and Deep.
Lieten, G.K. (2000). ‘Children Work and Education India: General
Parameters’ (part I), and ‘Field Work in 2 UP Village’ (part II).
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 35 No. 24: 2037-2043 and No.
25: 2171-2178.
Lieten. G.K. (2001). ‘Child Labour. Questions on Magnitude’. In: Lieten
and White: Child Labour. Policy Perspectives. Amsterdam: Aksant
Academic Publishers: 49-66.
Lieten, G.K. (2002). ‘Poverty of Numbers and Neglect of Poverty’. Paper,
3rd International Conference of the Association of Labour Historians,
March 14-16, 2002, Giri National Labour Institute, New Delhi. Mishra, G.P. and P.N. Pande (1996). Child Labour in the Glass Industry.
New Delhi: Nangia.
National Labour Institute (2000). Tools for Convergence. Noida: V.V.
Giri National Labour Institute (various booklets).
Ramachandran, Nira and Lionel Massun, eds. (2002). Coming to Grips
with Rural Child Work. A Food Security Approach. New Delhi:
Institute for Human Development.
Ravallion, M. and Wodon, Q. (2000). ‘Does Child Labour Displace
Schooling? Evidence on Behavioural Responses to an Enrolment
Subsidy’. The Economic Journal, Vol. 110, No. 402: 158-175 (also:
World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper, No. 2116).
Ray, Ranjan (1999) ‘How Child Labour and Child Schooling Interact
with Adult Labour’. Washington D.C., the World Bank, Policy
Research Working Paper, No. 2179.
Ray, Ranjan (2000a). ‘Analysis of Child Labour in Peru and Pakistan: A
Comparative Study’. Journal of Population Economics, No 13: 3-19.
Ray, Ranjan (2000b). ‘Child Labor, Child Schooling and their Interaction
with Adult Labor: Empirical Evidence from Peru and Pakistan’. The
World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 14 No 2: 34-67.
Rodgers, Gerry and Guy Standing (1981). The Economic Roles of
Children in Low-Income Countries. Geneva: ILO.
Sharma, Alakh N., Rajeev Sharma and Nikhil Raj (2001). The Impact of
Social Labelling on Child Labour in India’s Carpet Industry. New
Delhi: Institute for Human Development, report.
US Department of Labor (1994). By the Sweat and Toil of Children.
Volume 1. The Use of Child Labour in American Imports. Washington
D.C.
Weiner, Myron (1991). The Child and the State in India. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
कोई टिप्पणी नहीं:
एक टिप्पणी भेजें